Co-Director, Grantham Research
Institute on Climate Change and the Environment
Director, ESRC Centre for Climate
Change Economics and Policy
Professor, Dept. of Geography and Environment
"Losing the environment: the endowment effect and environmental
discounting" (with Frank Venmans), Centre for
Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper 264 and Grantham
Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working
Paper 233, 2016 (download)
It has recently been shown that, when discounting future
improvements in the environment, relative prices matter. However, we
argue relative prices are not the whole story. Not only is the
environment a consumption good in its own right, with a
corresponding environmental discount rate that depends on relative
scarcity, it also matters that we tend to be losing it. That is,
there is a considerable body of evidence from behavioural economics
and stated-preference valuation showing that we are loss-averse,
even in riskless choice settings. Therefore in this paper we
introduce reference dependence and loss aversion – the endowment
effect – to a model where welfare depends on consumption of a
produced good and of environmental quality. We show that the
endowment effect modifies the discount rate by introducing (i) an
instantaneous endowment effect and (ii) a reference-level effect.
Moreover we show that, when environmental quality is strictly
decreasing, these two effects mostly combine to dampen our usual
preference to smooth consumption over time – perhaps surprisingly,
the endowment effect increases the environmental discount rate on
these paths. In addition, on non-monotonic paths the endowment
effect can give rise to substantial discontinuities in the discount
rate.
"'Climate Value at Risk' of global financial assets" (with Alex
Bowen, Philip Gradwell and Charlie Dixon), Nature Climate Change,
2016 (link to
journal)
Investors and financial regulators are increasingly aware of
climate-change risks. So far, most of the attention has fallen on
whether controls on carbon emissions will strand the assets of
fossil-fuel companies. However, it is no less important to ask, what
might be the impact of climate change itself on asset values? Here
we show how a leading integrated assessment model can be used to
estimate the impact of twenty-first-century climate change on the
present market value of global financial assets. We find that the
expected ‘climate value at risk’ (climate VaR) of global financial
assets today is 1.8% along a business-as-usual emissions path.
Taking a representative estimate of global financial assets, this
amounts to US$2.5 trillion. However, much of the risk is in the
tail. For example, the 99th percentile climate VaR is 16.9%, or
US$24.2 trillion. These estimates would constitute a substantial
write-down in the fundamental value of financial assets. Cutting
emissions to limit warming to no more than 2°C reduces the climate
VaR by an expected 0.6 percentage points, and the 99th percentile
reduction is 7.7 percentage points. Including mitigation costs, the
present value of global financial assets is an expected 0.2% higher
when warming is limited to no more than 2°C, compared with business
as usual. The 99th percentile is 9.1% higher. Limiting warming to no
more than 2°C makes financial sense to risk-neutral investors—and
even more so to the risk averse.
"The risk of climate ruin" (with Nick Silver and
Oliver Bettis), Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy
Working Paper 243 and Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change
and the Environment Working Paper 217, 2015 (download)
How large a risk is society prepared to run with the climate
system? One perspective on this is to compare the risk that the
world is running with the climate system, defined in terms of the
risk of ‘climate ruin’, with the comparable risk that financial
institutions, in particular insurance companies, are prepared or
allowed to run with their own financial ruin. We conclude that, in
terms of greenhouse gas emissions today and in the future, the world
is running a higher risk with the climate system than financial
institutions, in particular insurance companies, would usually run
with their own solvency.
"The climate beta" (with Christian Gollier and
Louise Kessler), Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy
Working Paper 215 and Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change
and the Environment Working Paper 190, 2015 (download)
Reducing emissions of CO2 today is expected to
reduce climate damages in the future. In this paper, we examine the
question of whether fighting climate change has the additional
advantage of reducing the aggregate risk borne by future
generations. This raises the question of the ‘climate beta’, i.e.
the elasticity of climate damages with respect to a change in
aggregate consumption. Using the DICE integrated assessment model,
we show that the climate beta is positive and close to unity, due
above all to the effect of uncertainty about technological progress.
In estimating the social cost of carbon, this justifies using a
relatively larger rate to discount expected climate damages. On the
other hand, expected climate damages are themselves made larger by
this effect and overall the NPV of emissions reductions today is
increased by the climate beta.
"Running with the red queen: an integrated assessment of land
expansion and global biodiversity decline (with Bruno Lanz and Tim
Swanson), Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the
Environment Working Paper 167, 2014 (download)
Modern agriculture relies on a small number of highly productive
crops and the continued expansion of agricultural land area has led
to a significant loss of biodiversity. In this paper we consider the
macroeconomic consequences of a continued expansion of modern
agriculture from the perspective of agricultural productivity and
food production: as the genetic material supporting agriculture
declines, pests and pathogens become more likely to adapt to crops
and proliferate, increasing crop losses due to biological hazards.
To evaluate the macroeconomic consequences of a reduction in
agricultural productivity associated with the expansion of
agriculture, we employ a quantitative, structurally estimated model
of the global economy in which economic growth, population and food
demand, agricultural innovations, and the process of land conversion
are jointly determined. We show that even a small impact of global
biodiversity on agricultural productivity calls for both a halt in
agricultural land conversion and increased agricultural R&D in order
to maintain food production associated with population and income
growth.
"Global population growth, technology and Malthusian
constraints: A quantitative growth theoretic perspective" (with Bruno Lanz and Tim
Swanson), International Economic Review, accepted(download
the working paper)
We study the interactions between global population,
technological progress, per capita income, the demand for food, and
agricultural land expansion over the period 1960 to 2100. We
formulate a two-sector Schumpeterian growth model with a Barro-Becker
representation of endogenous fertility. A manufacturing sector
provides a consumption good and an agricultural sector provides food
to sustain contemporaneous population. Total land area available for
agricultural production is finite, and the marginal cost of
agricultural land conversion is increasing with the amount of land
already converted, creating a potential constraint to population
growth. Using 1960 to 2010 data on world population, GDP, total
factor productivity growth and crop land area, we structurally
estimate the parameters determining the cost of fertility,
technological progress and land conversion. The model closely fits
observed trajectories, and we employ the model to make projections
from 2010 to 2100. Our results suggest a population slightly below
10 billion by 2050, further growing to 12 billion by 2100. As
population and per capita income grow, the demand for agricultural
output increases by almost 70% in 2050 relative to 2010. However,
agricultural land area stabilizes by 2050 at roughly 10 percent
above the 2010 level: growth in agricultural output mainly relies on
technological progress and capital accumulation.
"Spaces for agreement: a theory of Time-Stochastic Dominance and an
application to climate change" (with Nicoleta Anca Matei),
Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists
3(1), 85-130, 2016 (link
to journal)(download
the working paper)
Many investments involve both a long time horizon and risky
returns. Making investment decisions thus requires assumptions about
time and risk preferences. Such assumptions are frequently
contested, particularly in the public sector, and there is no
immediate prospect of universal agreement. Motivated by these
observations, we develop a theory and method of finding “spaces for
agreement.” These are combinations of classes of discount and
utility function, for which one investment dominates another (or
“almost” does so), so that all those whose preferences can be
represented by such combinations would agree on the option to
choose. The theory combines the insights of stochastic dominance and
time dominance and offers a nonparametric approach to intertemporal,
risky choice. We then apply the theory to climate change and show
using a popular simulation model that even tough carbon emissions
targets would be chosen by almost everyone, barring those with
arguably “extreme” preferences.
"Tall tales and fat tails: the science and economics of extreme
warming" (with Raphael Calel and David Stainforth), Climatic
Change, 132(1), 127-141, 2015(link
to journal) (download
paper) (download
SI)
It has recently been highlighted that the economic value of
climate mitigation depends sensitively on the slim possibility of
extreme warming. This insight has been obtained through a focus on
the fat upper tail of the climate sensitivity probability
distribution. However, while climate sensitivity is undoubtedly
important, what ultimately matters is transient temperature change.
A focus on transient temperature change stresses the interplay of
climate sensitivity with other physical uncertainties, notably
effective heat capacity. In this paper we present a conceptual
analysis of the physical uncertainties in economic models of climate
mitigation, leading to an empirical application of the DICE model,
which investigates the interaction of uncertainty in climate
sensitivity and the effective heat capacity. We expand on previous
results exploring the sensitivity of economic evaluations to the
tail of the climate sensitivity distribution alone, and demonstrate
that uncertainty about the system's effective heat capacity also
plays a very important role. We go on to discuss complementary
avenues of economic and scientific research that may help provide a
better combined understanding of the physical and economic processes
associated with a rapidly warming world.